Showing 21 - 30 of 35
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009731549
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003730533
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003730535
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003660206
We show how incorporating Gilboa, Maccheroni, Marinacci, and Schmeidler's (2010) notion of objective rationality into the α-MEU model of choice under ambiguity (Hurwicz, 1951) can overcome several challenges faced by the baseline model without objective rationality. The decision-maker (DM) has...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012255858
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011427980
Economists often estimate economic models on data and use the point estimates as a stand-in for the truth when studying the model’s implications for optimal decision-making. This practice ignores model ambiguity, exposes the decision problem to misspecification, and ultimately leads to...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014487318
Loss aversion postulates that people prefer avoiding losses over acquiring gains of equal size. It is a central part of prospect theory and, according to Daniel Kahneman, “the most significant contribution of psychology to behavioral economics” (Kahneman, 2011, p. 300). It has powerful...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014487321
Current time allocation and household production models face three major weaknesses: First, they only describe the average time allocation. Thus, information about the order of activities is lost. Therefore, it is impossible to describe the influence of activities on later ones. Such...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014480143
Behavioral economics has so far largely avoided discussing the psychological origins of preferences, as well as their relation to needs. This has not only restricted interdisciplinary exchange, but also significantly limits the predictive capabilities of models. For example, the revealed...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014480164