Showing 1 - 10 of 305
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003712723
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003279810
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003854494
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003748711
"Urban economists understand housing prices with a spatial equilibrium approach that assumes people must be indifferent across locations. Since the spatial no arbitrage condition is inherently imprecise, other economists have turned to different no arbitrage conditions, such as the prediction...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003626686
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001852426
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001877716
When there are binding price controls, there are shortages and the allocation of goods across consumers may not be efficient. In general, the misallocation costs of price controls are first order, while the classic welfare losses due to undersupply are second order. This paper presents an...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10013221092
In Manhattan and elsewhere, housing prices have soared over the 1990s. Rising incomes, lower interest rates, and other factors can explain the demand side of this increase, but some sluggishness on the supply of apartment buildings also is needed to account for the high and rising prices. In a...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10013244762
Urban economists understand housing prices with a spatial equilibrium approach that assumes people must be indifferent across locations. Since the spatial no arbitrage condition is inherently imprecise, other economists have turned to different no arbitrage conditions, such as the prediction...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012750289