Showing 1 - 10 of 10
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003756099
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001761690
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003735522
The effects of appropriability on invention have been well studied, but there has been little analysis of the effect of appropriability on the commercialization of existing inventions. Exploiting a database of 805 attempts by private firms to commercialize inventions licensed from the...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009191970
At least since Arrow (1962), the effects of appropriability on invention have been well studied, but there has been little analysis of the effect of appropriability on the commercialization of existing inventions. Exploiting a database of 805 attempts by private firms to commercialize inventions...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005778132
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10006968685
At least since Arrow (1962), the effects of appropriability on invention have been well studied, but there has been little analysis of the effect of appropriability on the commercialization of existing inventions. Exploiting a database of 805 attempts by private firms to commercialize inventions...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012468963
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10008045604
The effects of appropriability on invention have been well studied, at least since Arrow (1962), but there has been little analysis of the effect of approbriability on the commercialization of existing inventions. Exploiting a database of 966 attempts by private firms to commercialize inventions...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014027661
At least since Arrow (1962), economists have believed that strong property rights are necessary for firms to invest in innovation. This belief was a key principle underlying the Bayh-Dole Act, which gave universities the right to own and license federally funded inventions, because the...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014030972