Showing 91 - 100 of 127
Different social planners may have different opinions on the well-being of individuals under different social options (Roberts, 1980). If utilities are translation- or ratio-scale measurable, or if the social ranking might be incomplete, or if interplanner comparability is allowed; then there...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005155492
A set of outcomes for a transferable utility game in characteristic function form is dominant if it is, with respect to an outsider-independent dominance relation, accessible (or admissible) and closed. This outsider-independent dominance relation is restrictive in the sense that a deviating...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010494307
A set of outcomes for a TU-game in characteristic function form is dominant if it is, with respect to an outsider-independent dominance relation, accessible (or admis-sible) and closed. This outsider- independent dominance relation is restrictive in the sense that a deviating coalition cannot...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005062371
We investigate the mechanism that provides the optimal decision rule for two agents making joint decisions. It is shown that, a special rectangular mechanism with two sided screening, elicit correct information when agents?preferences are private information. Such mechanism is presented as a...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005739748
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005678357
We study divisor methods, the primary class to solve apportionment problems, based upon Stolarsky means Saß. These encompass the five traditional methods. We disclose a one-to-one relation between methods of the form Sa1 and aggregate measures of seat/vote disproportionality of the generalized...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005200726
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005046748
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10006996560
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10008214719
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10008221564