Showing 1 - 10 of 47
The poor can and do save, but often use formal or informal instruments that have high risk, high cost, and sub-optimal design. This could lead to undersaving compared to a world without market or behavioral frictions. Undersaving has important welfare consequences: variable consumption, low...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009769238
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010202943
The poor can and do save, but often use formal or informal instruments that have high risk, high cost, and limited functionality. This could lead to undersaving compared to a world without market or behavioural frictions. Undersaving can have important welfare consequences: variable consumption,...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010339591
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010457554
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012111887
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011915621
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011821666
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014336078
The poor can and do save, but often use formal or informal instruments that have high risk, high cost, and limited functionality. This could lead to undersaving compared to a world without market or behavioral frictions. Undersaving can have important welfare consequences: variable consumption,...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10013071844
The poor can and do save, but often use formal or informal instruments that have high risk, high cost, and limited functionality. This could lead to undersaving compared to a world without market or behavioral frictions. Undersaving can have important welfare consequences: variable consumption,...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10013063476