Showing 1 - 10 of 2,334
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012121057
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014512907
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001141836
The standard neoclassical growth model with Cobb-Douglas production predicts a monotonically declining saving rate, when reasonably calibrated. Ample empirical evidence, however, shows that the transition path of a country's saving rate exhibits a rising or non-monotonic pattern. In important...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009756310
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009689514
The standard neoclassical growth model with Cobb-Douglas production predicts a monotonically declining saving rate, when reasonably calibrated. Ample empirical evidence, however, shows that the transition path of a country's saving rate exhibits a rising or non-monotonic pattern. In important...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009736293
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001433443
Within the context of the neoclassical growth model I investigate the implications of (initial) endowment inequality when the rich have a higher marginal savings rate than the poor. More unequal societies grow faster in the transition process, and therefore exhibit a higher speed of convergence....
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014212117
In this short note I clarify two features of Figure 2.3 in Barro and Sala-i-Martin [2004]. The figure, as it appeared in the first and second editions of the book, is confusing if not wrong. I hope this note will serve as a corrigendum to the figure
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012718462
The standard neoclassical growth model with Cobb-Douglas production predicts a monotonically declining saving rate, when reasonably calibrated. Ample empirical evidence, however, shows that the transition path of a country’s saving rate exhibits a rising or non-monotonic pattern. In important...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014157373