Showing 1 - 10 of 56
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10000957930
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10000920587
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001329055
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001200669
"Building on Eaton and Kortum's (2002) model of Ricardian trade, Alvarez and Lucas (2005) calculate that a small country representing 1% of the world's GDP experiences a gain of 41% as it goes from autarky to frictionless trade with the rest of the world. But the gains from openness, which...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003618825
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003401503
Falling costs of coordination and communication have allowed firms in rich countries to fragment their production process and offshore an increasing share of the value chain to low-wage countries. Popular discussions about the aggregate impact of this phenomenon on rich countries have stressed...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012465450
Industrial agglomerations or `clusters` arise in the presence of industry-specific and local externalities, also called Marshallian externalities. The standard argument is that such externalities may justify a policy of infant-industry protection to allow and encourage clusters to emerge. This...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010327174
There is a common perception that low productivity or low growth is due to what can be called an `innovation shortfall,` usually identified as a low rate of investment in research and development (RD) compared with some high-innovation countries. The usual reaction to this perceived problem is...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010327177
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10000952754