Showing 1 - 10 of 32
We define social reciprocity as the act of demonstrating one's disapproval, at some personal cost, for the violation of widely-held norms (e.g., don't free ride). Social reciprocity differs from standard notions of reciprocity because social reciprocators intervene whenever a norm is violated...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010271935
When a strategic situation arises repeatedly, the possibility arises that equilibrium predictions can be justified by a dynamic adjustment process. We examine myopic adjustment dynamics, a class that includes replicator dynamics from evolutionary game theory, simple models of imitation, models...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012235814
interactions. The second model captures the evolution of a society of motivated agents. It is demonstrated that misperception, when …
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011709868
In a recent paper Bagwell (1995) pointed out that only the Cournot outcome, but not the Stackelberg outcome, can be supported by a pure Nash equilibrium when actions of the Stackelberg leader are observed with the slightest error. The Stackelberg outcome, however, remains close to the outcome of...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010310808
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011339423
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010505476
interactions. The second model captures the evolution of a society of motivated agents. It is demonstrated that misperception, when …
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10011384060
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010235294
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014024361
This chapter reviews and integrates much of what has been learned on the processes of technological evolution, their … main features, and their effects on the evolution of industries. First, we map and integrate the various pieces of evidence …
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014025173