Showing 201 - 210 of 286
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10002800448
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10002803659
The Petersburg Paradox and its solutions are formulated in a uniform arrangement centered around d'Alembert's ratio test. All its aspects are captured using three mappings, a mapping from the natural numbers to the space of the winnings, a utility function defined on the space of the winnings,...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010308279
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10001366462
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012876592
Common ratio effects should be ruled out if subjects' preferences satisfy compound independence, reduction of compound lotteries, and coalescing. In other words, at least one of these axioms should be violated in order to generate a common ratio effect. Relying on a simple experiment, we...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010886877
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010902850
Schumpeter took a great interest in actual fiscal policy, first, during ?9?8 and ?9?9 to rescue Austria’s economic position and currency in the aftermath of World War i. These reform proposals pertain to situations of extreme economic misery. For reforms of the fiscal system under normal...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010902934
The Petersburg Paradox and its solutions are formulated in a uniform arrangement centered around d'Alembert's ratio test. All its aspects are captured using three mappings, a mapping from the natural numbers to the space of the winnings, a utility function defined on the space of the winnings,...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010954825
In 1713 Nicolas Bernoulli sent to de Montmort several mathematical problems, the fifth of which was at odds with the then prevailing belief that the advantage of games of hazard follows from their expected value. In spite of the infinite expected value of this game, no gambler would venture a...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010954833