Showing 111 - 120 of 252
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009945781
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009905286
According to the “relative income hypothesis,” decision makers derive positive utility from identifying with a group that performs more poorly than they do. We hypothesize that decision makers simultaneously derive negative utility from identifying with such a group. The reason is that...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10013244830
There are two kinds of beliefs. If the ultimate objective is wellbeing (utility), the generated beliefs are “practical.” If the ultimate objective is truth, the generated beliefs are “scientific.” This article defends the practical/scientific belief distinction. The proposed distinction...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010988749
In orthodox economics, honesty or integrity is treated as either part of the constraint function or the objective function. This is at the origin of the statement, “every man has his price.” However, if integrity has a price, why do agents experience shame when they sell it while they do not...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005252504
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005371356
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005155608
Neoclassical and Marxian theorists have generally failed to explain entrepreneurship, and for an obvious reason. To apply the calculus of optimization, neoclassical theorists have to treat the set of resources as an object that exists 'initself,' i.e., independent of the acting subject. On the...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009215373
Are there empirical anomalies upon which Dewey's theory of action sheds better light than existing neoclassical and heterodox approaches? This introduction answers in the affirmative. They are the set of anomalies highlighted by behavioral economics. These anomalies stress the centrality of...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009219366
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10009219394