Showing 141 - 150 of 315
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005355679
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005361593
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005362444
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005362513
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005364605
Voting procedures focus on the aggregation of individuals' preferences to produce collective decisions. In practice, a voting procedure is characterized by ballot responses and the way ballots are tallied to determine winners. Voters are assumed to have clear preferences over candidates and...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005367396
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369313
In the first competitive election for President of the Social Choice and Welfare Society, the (official) approval-voting winner differed from the (hypothetical) Borda count winner, who was also the Condorcet winner. But because the election was essentially a toss-up, it is impossible to say who...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369390
This paper focuses on the fair division of a set of indivisible items between two people when both have the same linear preference order on the items but may have different preferences over subsets of items. Surprisingly, divisions that are envy-free, Pareto-optimal, and ensure that the less...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369413
Riker's size principle for n-person zero-sum games predicts that winning coalitions that form will be minimal in that any player's defection will negate the coalition's winning status. Brams and Fishburn (1995) applied Riker's principle to weighted-majority voting games in which players have...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369434