Showing 21 - 30 of 130
Despite interesting work on infectious diseases by such economists as Peter Francis, Michael Kremer, and Tomas Philipson, the literature does not set out the general structure of externalities involved in the prevention, and care of such diseases. The authors identify two kinds of externality....
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005133633
The author applies to the health sector an approach to analyzing projects advocated in a recent paper by Devarajan, Squire, and Suthiwart-Narueput. In the health sector, a project evaluation should: 1) Establish a firm justification for public involvement. The author identifies a number of...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005133880
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005516221
The assumption of rational choice helps in understanding how people respond to infectious diseases. People maximize their well-being by choosing levels of prevention and therapy subject to the constraints they face. Objectives and constraints are numerous, necessitating tradeoffs. For example,...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005446701
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005239638
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005175652
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005316211
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005323956
The structure of representative agents and decentralisation of the social planner's problem provide a framework for the economics of infection and associated externalities. Optimal implementation of prevention and therapy depends on: (1) biology including whether infection is person to person or...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005393061
As governments grow richer, the share of their GDP devoted to public spending rises. Public spending in the United States was 7.5 percent of GDP in 1913. It is 33 percent today. Although industrial countries spend twice as much as developing countries, government spending on goods and services...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005080048