Showing 1 - 10 of 241
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10002095136
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10002095340
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10014606789
The theory of games against nature relies on complete preferences among all conceivable acts (case 1). Aumann and Drèze (Am Econ J Microecon 1(1):116,(2009) consider situations where preferences are defined only for a given set of acts (case 2).We extend these results to situations where (i)...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010317103
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10003056868
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10002067904
The label quot;Keynes-Negishi equilibriaquot; is attached here to equilibria in a monetary economy with imperfectly competitive product and labor markets where business firms and labor unions hold demand perceptions with kinks - as posited in Negishi's 1979 book Microeconomic Foundations of...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012728674
We propose an extension of the standard general equilibrium model with production and incomplete markets to situations in which (i) private investors have limited information on the returns of specific assets, (ii) managers of firms have limited information on the preferences of individual...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012730378
In recent decades, the concept of subjective probability has been increasingly applied to an adversary's choices in strategic games. A careful examination reveals that the standard construction of subjective probabilities does not apply in this context. We show how the difficulty may be overcome...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012734558
Modern game theory was born in 1928,when John von Neumann published his Minimax Theorem. This theorem ascribes to all two-person zero-sum games a value - what rational players may expect - and optimal strategies - how they should play to achieve that expectation. Seventy-seven years later,...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10012734559