Showing 1 - 10 of 10
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369271
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369288
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369404
In pure population problems, a single resource is to be distributed equally among the agents in a society, and the social planner chooses population size(s) and per-capita consumption(s) for each resource constraint and set of feasible population sizes within the domain of the solution. This...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369463
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10010539412
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005178637
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005596362
In this article, the kinds of utility comparisons that can be made may differ in distinct population subgroups. Within each subgroup, utility is either ordinally or cardinally measurable. Levels and differences of utility may or may not be interpersonally comparable within a subgroup. No utility...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369266
Arrow's axioms for social welfare functions are shown to be inconsistent when the set of alternatives is the nonnegative orthant in a multidimensional Euclidean space and preferences are assumed to be either the set of analytic classical economic preferences or the set of Euclidean spatial...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005369321
In Harsanyi's impartial observer theorem, an impartial observer determines a social ordering of the lotteries on the set of social alternatives based on a sympathetic but impartial concern for all individuals in society. This ordering is derived from a more primitive ordering on the set of all...
Persistent link: https://www.econbiz.de/10005596466